Solid Waste & Recycling

Feature

Where do eco-fees come from?

The political fixation on “doing something about” eco-fees is akin to fretting about a lingering cough while ignoring the underlying pneumonia that is its cause. If eco-fees are the symptomatic “cough” then government...


The political fixation on “doing something about” eco-fees is akin to fretting about a lingering cough while ignoring the underlying pneumonia that is its cause. If eco-fees are the symptomatic “cough” then government product stewardship policies that restrict or lessen competition between producers in end-of-life product management are the causative “pneumonia.”

Let’s consider two producers of widgets: Producer X and Producer Y.

In the free market Producer X can collect and recycle its recycling-friendly widgets for $3/unit while Producer Y spends $5/unit to collect and recycle its less eco-friendly widgets.

Along comes the helping hand of government, which sanctions the creation of the Widget Stewardship Agency (WSA). The government allows widget producers to sign up with the WSA collective, which then assumes the subscribing companies’ obligations and liabilities. The WSA sets a widget recycling eco-fee of $4/unit that each subscribing producer pays on each widget it supplies into the market.

Company X now has two options:

1. Go along with all other widget producers party to the WSA and transfer its legal liability for widget recycling to that agency, while passing on the $4 widget eco-fee (exclusive of the product price) down its supply chain via the retailer to the consumer; or

2. Forgo subscription to WSA, recycle its own widgets and have the $3/unit recycling cost eat into its profit margin (recognizing that no retailer is going to set their point-of-sale systems up to levy a special $3 eco-fee just for Producer X).

Simply stated, Producers X’s choices are to go along with other producers in passing on of a fixed $4/unit separate eco-fee or, alternatively, forgo $3/unit in profit margin. What choice do you suppose it will make?

Of course producer Y will be happy to pass along the $4/unit eco-fee: it’s less than the actual cost of processing Y’s harder-to-recycle widgets. Oh, and X’s competitive advantage is lost in the process.

This is an example of what is essentially stewardship agency-based eco-fee “price-fixing” — the less recyclable widget is subsidized while the competitive advantage of the more recyclable widget is lost. Plus, the consumer loses because no producer has any incentive to compete and innovate in order to bring the costs of widget recycling down.

Of course, as the sole buyer of widget recycling (WSA is a buying monopoly or “monopsony”) the WSA can squeeze down recycling service provider prices at a whim.

Where the government allows the WSA to set and enforce environmental standards, WSA can cut costs by simply ignoring the environmental standards and squeezing down what’s paid to recyclers.

There should be no surprise that under this “fox guarding the henhouse” approach widgets end up being processed in poor conditions in South Asia or that more sophisticated recycling service companies are unwilling to invest (because their less diligent counterparts become more competitive through WSA sanctioned corner-cutting).

Conversely, in a competitive producer market, with environmental standards set and maintained by an impartial third party, reduction in widget recycling costs is the result of innovation and not the crushing weight of a producer purchasing monopoly. In a free market, recyclers compete for producers’ widget recycling business by reducing costs through innovation in recycling practices and technologies. And companies like X and Y have an incentive to make their widgets longer lasting, reusable, or at least easily recycled. (Because they’re paying for it.)

So, if people are nonplussed or angered by eco-fees, there’s a simple solution: preserve competition between producers in how they discharge their end-of-life recycling obligations. Make each producer individually accountable for the environmental outcomes associated with their end-of-life widgets. And don’t shield widget producers and widget recyclers from Canada’s competition laws.

After Ontario’s eco-fee controversy in the summer of 2010, Professor Don Dewees and I called for such an approach. Ontario’s draft Bill 91, the Waste Reduction Act (WRA) is supposedly directed at achieving this outcome. The draft bill is out for public comment. (See Cover Story, page 8, and Regulation Roundup, page XX.)

While the WRA’s integrated pricing requirement purports to, “…promote the reduction of environmental impacts by requiring the integration of the environmental protection costs of products …” existing eco-fees are not the product of a competitive producer market and, as such, the integrated pricing requirement could be seen as little more than hiding a tax.

Whether the WRA, perhaps with modifications, will truly achieve the objectives of IPR remains to be seen. This will be the subject of future columns, in print and on this magazine’s website, plus a special report planned for the fall.

by Usman Valiante is Principal of Corporate Policy Group in Orangeville, Ontario. Contact Usman at valiante@corporatepolicygroup.com


Print this page

Related Posts



Have your say:

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

*